
Viewpoints | Jun 19,2021
Sep 6 , 2025
By Keun Lee
Financialisation, the growing influence of financial markets and shareholder value over corporate strategy, differs from financial development, which expands access to credit and financial services. In this commentary provided by Project Syndicate (PS), Keun Lee, a professor of economics at Seoul National University, argues that while innovation and financial development can boost growth and jobs, unchecked financialisation may quietly reshape the social contract in advanced and emerging economies alike.
Over a decade ago, Nobel laureates Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, together with their co-author Thierry Verdier, contrasted America's "cutthroat" brand of capitalism with Western Europe's "cuddly" version. The qualities that make cutthroat capitalism more conducive to innovation, they argued, also lead to higher levels of inequality, while cuddly reward structures tend to lead to lower growth and higher welfare. Today, inequality is soaring, notably in the United States.
Do policies aimed at boosting innovation risk make a bad situation worse?
In the economics literature, one can find plenty of support for the idea that technological innovation is a key driver of inequality. But another important line of thinking attributes rising inequality largely to "financialisation," a term that encompasses the financial sector's growing share in the economy, the increasing reliance of non-financial firms on financial activities as a revenue source, and corporate governance focused on maximising dividends for shareholders, rather than investing in future growth.
My co-author Juneyoung Lee and I recently sought to shed light on which factor has a greater role in driving inequality. We grouped countries according to their levels of innovation and financialisation. We found the highest levels of inequality in the low-innovation and high-financialisation group, which includes a range of developed and emerging economies, such as Brazil, Spain, and Turkey. Inequality was also relatively high in the group where both innovation and financialisation were substantial, including most of the Anglo-American capitalist economies, as well as Japan and South Korea.
By contrast, the high-innovation and low-financialisation group, which includes many of Europe's advanced economies, such as Austria, Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, and Norway, showed the lowest levels of inequality. The low-innovation and low-financialisation group, which includes most of the emerging economies, such as India, Russia, and some Eastern European countries, has intermediate levels of inequality.
Ultimately, we found no link between innovation and income inequality. This finding challenges those of the French economist Phillippe Aghion, who argues that innovation, as measured by the quality-weighted number of patents, tends to exacerbate inequality, because the profits generated by the associated productivity gains become monopoly rents for the innovators. But, Aghion's approach fails to account for other effects of innovation, such as increased investment in physical capital, which can mitigate negative distributional effects by creating job opportunities and increasing the incomes of workers who work with the new systems or equipment.
These benefits are particularly robust when it comes to "product innovation" (the introduction of a new or updated good), because the new product generates a wave of new demand, which spurs increased investment. "Process innovation" (the introduction of a new method of production) is often labour-saving in the short run, but even here, the effect on inequality is typically offset in the longer term by cost savings.
Using the same measure of innovation as Aghion, but accounting for these factors, I have found that innovation does not affect overall inequality or the income share of the top one to five percent. The monopoly rents associated with innovations tend to be short-lived, as other firms eventually adopt the new technology.
This brings us back to financialisation, which is directly correlated with inequality, specifically, the gutting of the middle class. As the ratio of stock-market capitalisation, or of stocks traded, to GDP rises, income is redistributed from the middle class to top earners. (The incomes of the bottom 50pc are not necessarily affected.)
This effect could be seen in the US after the 2008 global financial crisis, when unprecedented monetary easing caused stock prices to rise, giving the illusion of a robust recovery, even as employment lagged and the real economy struggled. Similarly, in the third quarter of 2023, Japanese stock prices surged to record highs, owing to monetary easing and share buybacks, even though growth had been negative for the previous two quarters.
It is worth noting that financialisation (the influence of financial activities on non-financial firms) is not the same as financial development (the depth, accessibility, and capabilities of financial institutions). Financial development, measured as the ratio of private credit, or of liquid liabilities, to GDP, does not appear to have a significant effect on the income share held by the highest earners.
The message is clear. Policymakers concerned about inequality should not fear technological innovation or financial development, which will lead to growth and jobs in the long run. But they should consider steps to mitigate the distributional consequences of financialisation, such as raising taxes on the financial incomes of the wealthiest households. If they do nothing, the decline of the middle class will continue.
PUBLISHED ON
Sep 06,2025 [ VOL
26 , NO
1323]
Viewpoints | Jun 19,2021
Commentaries | Apr 13, 2025
Editorial | Jan 16,2021
My Opinion | Aug 18,2024
Commentaries | Sep 07,2019
Radar | May 20,2023
Advertorials | Jun 05,2023
Viewpoints | Aug 10,2024
Commentaries | Apr 26,2025
Fortune News | Apr 27,2025
Photo Gallery | 149016 Views | May 06,2019
Photo Gallery | 139296 Views | Apr 26,2019
My Opinion | 134609 Views | Aug 14,2021
My Opinion | 131180 Views | Aug 21,2021
Dec 22 , 2024 . By TIZITA SHEWAFERAW
Charged with transforming colossal state-owned enterprises into modern and competitiv...
Aug 18 , 2024 . By AKSAH ITALO
Although predictable Yonas Zerihun's job in the ride-hailing service is not immune to...
Jul 28 , 2024 . By TIZITA SHEWAFERAW
Unhabitual, perhaps too many, Samuel Gebreyohannes, 38, used to occasionally enjoy a couple of beers at breakfast. However, he recently swit...
Jul 13 , 2024 . By AKSAH ITALO
Investors who rely on tractors, trucks, and field vehicles for commuting, transporting commodities, and f...
Sep 6 , 2025
The dawn of a new year is more than a simple turning of the calendar. It is a moment...
Aug 30 , 2025
For Germans, Otto von Bismarck is first remembered as the architect of a unified nati...
Aug 23 , 2025
Banks have a new obsession. After decades chasing deposits and, more recently, digita...
Aug 16 , 2025
A decade ago, a case in the United States (US) jolted Wall Street. An ambulance opera...
Sep 7 , 2025 . By BEZAWIT HULUAGER
Brook Taye (PhD), the chief executive of the Ethiopian Investment Holdings (EIH), is...
Sep 7 , 2025 . By BEZAWIT HULUAGER
For decades, Shemiz Tera in the Addis Ketema District of Atena tera has been a thrivi...
Sep 7 , 2025 . By NAHOM AYELE
A dream of affordable homeownership has dissolved into a courtroom showdown for hundr...
Sep 7 , 2025 . By YITBAREK GETACHEW
The federal tax officials' abrupt tax reform, which suspends the long-standing Turnov...